domingo, 22 de abril de 2012

Economics and Europe


Yesterday I was discussing a model of aggregate demand and supply with my students. It was basically an introduction to how growth happens and how it can bring about increases in the general level of prices. We discussed the differences in the view Neoclassical and Keynesian economists have of the aggregate supply curve (the total amount of goods an economy produces at different given price levels.) For the first group, markets always adjust and operate efficiently, so nothing the government does to stimulate demand will have real impact, save for an increase in the overall price level. For the Keynesians, instead, in times when the demand is too depressed (as seems to be the case now, with consumers not particularly euphoric and companies hoarding up cash instead of investing) any action taken by governments to stimulate it will reflect in higher levels of output at a very moderate cost in price stability. This is not a difficult concept to grasp, especially when taking into account the notion of circular flow of income: any extra dollar spent by the government will go to someone’s pocket, who is likely to spend part of it in something else, and part of that expenditure is likely to be spent again, and so on and so forth. So, the Keynesian argument goes, demand increases more than the original stimulus, and output increases accordingly.
Now, what is the battle horse of Neoclassicals? The idea that unfortunately seems to be dominating the debate, at least in Europe, is that governments need to create “business confidence.” And that firms are not going to be confident if they expect higher taxes in the future in order to finance governments’ expenditure. But let’s get it right. Firms produce in order to sell. Consumers are not able to afford buying much. And governments, allegedly, should focus in balancing budgets, by increasing taxes (not corporate taxes, as this could affect confidence) and reducing expenditure. How is this meant to work? An economy produces for consumers, for the government, for investors, and for the foreign sector. The first group is not buying, and with an increase in taxes chances are that they are going to buy even less. Governments have been asked to limit their expenditure. Firms will only invest if they see prospects of selling (to, ehrm, consumers and eventually the government). And unless we find a way to have the rest of the world demanding more of our products (a very difficult thing to do for a country that cannot depreciate its currency, as all Eurozone-troubled economies are,) production is not going to increase by means of just letting markets operate.
I didn’t say all this to my students; I just proposed the two models. Obviously, they found the Keynesian one far more convincing. When I asked what should governments in Europe be doing these days, the answer was obvious: reduce taxes and increase government expenditure. What are they doing instead? Fussing all around about austerity measures, about the possibility of an increase in inflation, when inflation rates are below 3%, more than one point below the rate in mid-2008.
In less than an hour, my 16-year old students could understand why Europe is so much in need of real action if it wants to get out of its trouble and prevents its citizens, particularly the younger ones, from having to go through unnecessary hardship. But unfortunately the political arena seems to be dominated more by ideology than by an unbiased understanding of how the market operates.